In my research on the Great Depression, I noticed that an interesting correlation developed in the middle of 1931. But first a bit of background. Germany had major debt problems after WWI, partly due to the unfortunate Allied decision to impose large war reparations. After a series of negotiations, Germany issued “Young Plan Bonds” in 1929 to help finance these debts. There was initially a high level of confidence in these bonds. However as the Depression worsened, Germany’s manufacturing sector was hit quite hard. Banking trouble developed. And the Nazi party began to make political gains, partly due to its opposition to war debts.
In the middle of 1931 the price of Young Plan bonds suddenly became highly correlated with the US DJIA. Indeed the actual correlation was even stronger than estimated in the table below, as the markets closed at different times.
Table 5.1 The Relationship Between Variations in the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DLDOW), and the Price of Young Plan Bonds (DLYPB), Sept. 1930 – Dec. 1931, Selected Periods, Daily.
Dependent Variable – DLDJIA
Sample Number of Coefficient Adjusted Durban-
Period Observations on DLYPB T-Statistic R-squared Watson
1. 9/14/30 – 9/30/30 14 .5492 2.18 .225 2.69
2. 12/31/30 – 3/20/31 65 .1202 0.71 .000 2.19
3. 3/20/31 – 5/1/31 35 .5714 2.12 .094 2.59
4. 5/1/31 – 6/19/31 41 -.1084 -0.54 .000 1.94
5. 6/19/31 – 7/30/31 34 .4559 5.05 .426 1.96
6. 7/30/31 – 9/17/31 40 .3554 3.78 .254 2.39
7. 9/17/31 – 11/6/31 41 .2888 3.85 .257 2.40
8. 11/6/31 – 12/30/31 43 .2801 3.72 .234 2.33
9. 12/30/31 – 3/31/32 75 .2617 4.03 .171 1.80
10. 3/31/32 – 6/30/32 77 .3152 3.75 .147 2.30
11. 6/30/32 – 9/30/32 76 .0799 0.66 .000 1.92
__________________________________________________________________
Those R2 figures for late 1931 and early 1932 may not look that impressive, but they are actually extraordinarily high, especially for daily first differences of asset prices. If you read the NYT year end report on stocks, by month, there is no discussion of Germany in the first 6 months. In the final six months Germany is mentioned in every single monthly summary. People saw what was happening. Furthermore, the correlation tended to jump up at times with heavy German news, further evidence of the direction of causation. So that’s not really at issue, the dispute is over why German debt problems impacted US stock prices.
Those who don’t believe monetary shocks are important would point to German debt held by US banks, or the fact that Germany is an important export market of the US. But then why did the correlation suddenly jump up when the debt crisis began to coincide with stresses on the international monetary system?
My view is that the German crisis led to a loss of confidence in their currency and perhaps other currencies as well. This led to gold hoarding, as gold was the ultimate source of liquidity, the medium of account in most major economies. More demand for gold means a higher value of gold, and that means deflation for any country on the gold standard. And according to the supposedly “discredited” Phillips Curve, deflation means job losses and lower stock values, even in real terms.
How could we test this theory? Ideally you’d want a country that’s way too small to have any direct real effects on the world economy. But big enough where it might cause a chain reaction, which would lead to an increase in demand for the ultimate source of liquidity in the 21st century world economy. Which is, of course, the US dollar. Ideally it would be a tiny country of no more than 10 million people, containing little villages with donkeys walking down the street. Not a big industrial powerhouse like Germany, which might have important real effects.
Then you’d want to see if financial turmoil in that small country could dramatically impact stock values in the US, even though US banks held relatively little of that country’s debt. And dramatically impact stock prices in East Asia, which is part of the dollar bloc but has even less of that country’s debt. In other words, a country like Greece.
As far as I’m concerned, my conjecture as to what happened in 1931 is now pretty much confirmed. When I see daily reports of the effects of Greece on the world economy, it seems just like Germany in July 1931. When I see it spread to Italy, it seems just like Britain, in September 1931. When I see daily reports of Italian bond yields in the US media, it seems just like news of the Young Plan bonds, which was reported almost daily in the US financial press during 1931. Yes, it’s 1931 all over again.
So what is the solution? I hate to tell you this, but the problem is even harder to solve today than in 1931. Yes, most countries were tied down by gold in 1931 (what Barry Eichengreen called “golden fetters.”) But at least they had their own currencies, which could be easily devalued. Now even that option is gone. And despite all the pain, 70% of Greeks oppose giving up the euro. This crisis isn’t ending anytime soon.
And I really don’t even know what the optimal solution is. In isolation, you could argue that Greece should leave the euro, just as one could recommend that the UK devalue in 1931. But the British devaluation made things much worse for those countries still on the gold standard.
So maybe Greece should just tough it out. But then in retrospect the attempt of the major countries to “tough it out” in the 1930s was what made the Great Depression so great. Most economic historians think the optimal solution was for them all to have devalued right away. But if even Greece is highly reluctant to devalue, just imagine those countries that are still nowhere near in as bad shape.
The real lesson of 1931 is like that old joke about the guy who asks directions to Dodge City, and is told “first of all, if you want to go to Dodge City you shouldn’t be starting from here.” The best solution to the euro crisis is to not set up a single currency in the first place.
Tyler Cowen has recently done some very depressing posts discussing the way the euro crisis is likely to play out. I don’t have a strong opinion on this issue, because every alternative seems unacceptable. But I will say that his scenario is not all that unlike the way things actually did play out in Europe during 1931-36, as the first to leave were the weakest countries, but by 1936 even France devalued. In monetary terms, France was the Germany of the 1930s. French hoarding of gold made the gold standard crisis worse, just as German demands for tight money at the ECB are making the euro crisis worse today. By 1936 the deflationary effects of French policy rebounded against France herself, in a weird sort of cosmic justice. Something to think about in Berlin.
PS. I don’t want to push the comparison too far. The Greek government really did behave recklessly in the years leading up to the 2008 crisis, hiding the scale of their debt problems. And Italian voters kept electing Berlusconi, with predictable results.
PPS. I apologize if I haven’t answered your email. Still very busy, but feel a need to keep posting.